Wednesday, November 14, 2012
A free market for ideas has long been respected in China as a political ideal.
Nobel Prize–winning economist Ronald Coase and Professor Ning Wang on the transformation of the Chinese economy.
Editor's note: Nobel Prize–winning economist Ronald Coase and Professor Ning Wang are the authors of a new book, "How China Became Capitalist."
The book outlines China’s 30-year transition from a closed, communist,
agrarian economy to a rapidly growing industrial economy. THE AMERICAN
Editor-in-Chief Nick Schulz recently asked the authors about the
transformation of the Chinese economy, the legacy of the Tiananmen
massacre, and why “capitalism with Chinese characteristics is
impoverished by the lack of a free market for ideas.”
Nick Schulz: In a famous 1978
communiqué, communist party leaders in China admitted that “one of the
serious shortcomings in the structure of economic management is the
over-concentration of authority.” What prompted the Chinese leadership
to acknowledge this fact and embrace devolving economic authority?
Ronald Coase and Ning Wang:
This was not the first time for the Chinese leadership to acknowledge
the problem. As early as 1956, even before China’s first Five-Year Plan
(1953–1957) ended, Mao realized centralization of power in the Chinese
economy had dampened the incentives of local officials as well as those
of the state enterprises in cities and communes and production teams in
rural areas. Mao pushed decentralization in 1958, but it was quickly
absorbed into the “Great Leap Forward,” when more than 30 million
Chinese peasants perished in Mao’s great famine. In the eyes of Chinese
economic planners, decentralization was the culprit. Afterward,
centralization was restored.
By 1978, the Chinese government came back to Mao’s diagnosis, though
its prescription went one step further than Mao’s, since it knew that
Mao’s did not work. Mao devolved economic authorities only to provincial
and sub-provincial local governments. Now, state enterprises were given
some autonomy in their operation.
NS: You write that “China became capitalist with marginal revolutions.” What do you mean?
RC & NW: A
key empirical finding of our book is that there are actually two
Chinese reforms. One was dictated by Beijing. The other resulted from
grassroots initiatives. Starving peasants started private farming and
township and village enterprises; city residents without a job in the
state sector set up the first private businesses in Chinese cities;
Shenzhen and other Special Economic Zones were set up as an experiment
to co-opt capitalism to save socialism. They all operated outside the
protected boundary of socialism.
During the first decade of reform, “marginal revolutions” introduced
entrepreneurship and market forces back to the Chinese economy, while
the state-led reform was desperately trying to improve the state-owned
enterprises and save socialism. In this sense, China became capitalist
with marginal revolutions.
NS: You point out that China’s reforms of its state-owned enterprises were a disappointment. What accounted for that?
RC & NW: China’s reforms
of state enterprises as the “central link” of the whole reform program
lasted for more than two decades, from the very beginning to 2003.
Before the mid-1990s, privatization of state enterprises was strictly
prohibited, and reform mainly consisted of delegating some economic
rights to state enterprises and giving them some incentives. Even though
the state enterprises gained more autonomy and better incentive
structures, they were never subject to market discipline. For example,
poor-performing state enterprises were not allowed to go bankrupt. Not
surprisingly, state enterprises were quickly outperformed by private
enterprises, which were poorly equipped in terms of financial and human
capital but had to face strict market selection.
In the 1990s, increasing competition from the private sector made
more and more state enterprises insolvent, adding financial burden to
local governments. This led many local authorities to let go of the
state enterprises under their jurisdiction. Since the mid-1990s, the
Chinese government started to privatize state enterprises, and the
number of remaining state enterprises was reduced dramatically.
Today, the central government controls less than 120 state-owned
enterprises, but many of them are state monopolies, still not subject to
market discipline. As a special interest group, the remaining state
enterprises pose a serious challenge to market order.
NS: You write that in the
1980s, “The United States of America came to replace the Soviet Union as
a role model for China, particularly in the minds of Chinese students.”
How did that come to pass?
RC & NW: Ever since
Nixon’s visit to Beijing in 1972, China began to see the United States
not only as a partner in the Cold War, but also as a country leading the
world in science and education. Deng Xiaoping’s visit to the United
States in 1979 and ensuing visits to China made by many American
academic delegations further convinced the Chinese people that they had
much to learn from the United States.
Moreover, some of China’s leading scientists were trained in the
United States before 1949. They were denounced as “rightists” during
Mao’s time. Those who were fortunate to have survived Mao’s political
campaigns were gradually rehabilitated after Mao’s death, and returned
to their research and teaching. They encouraged their children and
students to go to the United States for study. Many senior Chinese
leaders also sent their children to the United States. When they were
young, many of them went to the Soviet Union for study.
Universities and even libraries in China were shut down during the
Cultural Revolution (1966–1976). Under Deng’s leadership, Chinese
universities were reopened in 1977. College students were desperate for
new knowledge and new sources of knowledge. It did not take long for
them to figure out that the United States had the best to offer.
Even though the Chinese Communist Party still monopolizes political
power, it is no longer an ideology-driven political party. Indeed, it is
communist only in name.
NS: The Student Movement and
the collapse of the Soviet Union led to deep antipathy on the part of
China’s communist leaders toward markets. Are you surprised that the
Tiananmen massacre did not ultimately lead to a full-scale rejection and
reversal of economic reforms?
RC & NW: China’s economic
reform was under heavy political and ideological attack from 1989 to
1991. Many market reforms were reversed. The private sector was
chastened as the root source of China’s political and economic problems.
Nonetheless, China kept its commitment to opening itself to the West.
Even the most conservative Chinese leaders realized that China could
not afford a return to isolation, and that China had too much to learn
from the West. On November 28, 1990, at the 10th anniversary of the
Special Economic Zone, Shenzhen was hailed as “a vanguard in conducting
reform and opening up to the outside world.”
Moreover, the first decade of reform had generated many economic
gains and improved the lives of so many Chinese that a full-scale
rejection of reform would jeopardize further the legitimacy of the
government. As long as pragmatism prevailed and the Chinese government
continued to “seek truth from facts,” China’s reform and opening up had a
great chance to survive.
NS: You write, “The most
extraordinary feature of Chinese economic reform is perhaps that the
Chinese Communist Party has survived, and indeed thrived, over the three
decades of market transformation.” What accounts for this survival and
thriving?
RC & NW: After Mao’s
death, the Chinese Communist Party quickly distanced itself from a
radical revolutionary party committed to fighting capitalism and
spreading communism. With the return of Deng Xiaoping in 1978, the new
party leadership returned to pragmatism and jettisoned radical ideology.
As the fledging private sector outperformed the state sector and the
marginal revolutions outshined the state-led reform, the party gradually
embraced the market economy.
Even though the Chinese Communist Party still monopolizes political
power, it is no longer an ideology-driven political party. Indeed, it is
communist only in name. It welcomes global capitalism and claims its
legitimacy on peace and prosperity. Its political philosophy is no
different from the “Mandate of Heaven.” It is this de-politicization of
the party, its continuous adaptation, and self-transformation that has
allowed the party to grow with the Chinese market economy.
Today, the Chinese government faces enormous challenges, including
corruption from within and the increasing demand for political
participation from without. As we have argued in the book, an open
market for ideas offers a gradual and viable path for China to further
reform its political system.
NS: You note that “capitalism
with Chinese characteristics is impoverished by the lack of a free
market for ideas.” What hope is there of that changing?
RC & NW: We are
cautiously optimistic that China in the coming decades will embrace the
market for ideas, just like it embraced the market for goods three
decades ago. Our optimism mainly rests on the following three
considerations. First, in the early 1980s Steve Cheung predicted that
China would go capitalist because the potential economic gains were
simply so overwhelming. Today, a similar but stronger argument can be
made for China’s move toward a market for ideas. Second, the market for
ideas is politically neutral. A market for ideas can work in many
different political systems. As long as the Chinese government continues
to commit itself to pragmatism, upholding practice as the criterion of
testing truth, it will come to realize that an open market for ideas is
indispensable for the Chinese people to realize their potential. Third, a
free market for ideas has long been respected in China as a political
ideal, as captured by the Chinese aphorism, “let a hundred flowers
bloom, and a hundred schools of thought contend.” Only an open market
for ideas can turn that dream into reality.
NS: You are critical of much
modern economics, saying it has been transformed “from a moral science
of man creating wealth to a cold logic of choice and resource
allocation.” How did this happen? Where did economics go wrong?
RC & NW: Adam Smith, the
founding father of modern economics, took economics as a study of “the
nature and causes of the wealth of nations.” As late as 1920, Alfred
Marshall in the eighth edition of Principles of Economics kept economics as “both a study of wealth and a branch of the study of man.” Barely a dozen years later, Lionel Robbins in his Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science
(1932) reoriented economics as “the science which studies human
behavior as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have
alternative uses.” Unfortunately, the viewpoint of Robbins has won the
day.
The fundamental shift from Smith and Marshall to Robbins is to rid
economics of its substance — the working of the social institutions that
bind together the economic system. Afterward, economics has turned into
a discipline without a subject matter, advocating itself as a study of
human choices. This shift has been assisted by what Hayek (1952)
criticized as the growing trend of scientism in the study of society,
which took mathematical formalism as the only secure route to truth in
the pursuit of knowledge. As economists become more and more interested
in formalism and related technical sophistication, it becomes secondary
whether the substantive questions that they choose to perfect their
methods or to illustrate their theoretical models bear any resemblance
to the real world economy. By and large, most of our colleagues are not
bothered by the fact that what they profess is mainly “blackboard
economics.”
We are now working with the University of Chicago Press to launch a new journal, Man and the Economy.
We chose our title carefully to signal the mission of the new journal,
which is to restore economics to a study of man as he is and of the
economy as it actually exists. We hope this new journal will provide a
platform to encourage scholars all over the world to study how the
economy works in their countries. We believe this is the only way to
make progress in economics.
We are very much aware that many of our colleagues whose work we
admire do not share our criticism of modern economics. But our goal is
not to replace one view of economics that we don’t like with another one
of our choice, but to bring diversity and competition to the
marketplace for economics ideas, which we hope most, if not all,
economists will endorse.
Nick Schulz is the editor of THE AMERICAN.
No comments:
Post a Comment