Don’t blame globalization for inequality – but rather policies hijacked by a few
Pranab Bardhan
YaleGlobal, 27 November 2012
Rich economy, poor management: China’s rich flaunt their wealth (top); India’s poor children wait for a mid-day meal | |
BERKELEY: Economic globalization in the sense of expansion of foreign
trade and investment is, of course, somewhat anemic, reflecting the
impact of global recession, although still vigorous in the sense of
continuous international transmission of technology, information, ideas
and social media.
But in the world of politics and policymaking a cold wind is blowing,
dimming earlier enthusiasm for global integration and market
liberalization. The Doha round of trade negotiations is moribund.
Economic integration in Europe is in disarray. Not merely is the fuming
against imports from China and immigrants from Mexico now a staple of
American electoral politics, the populist anger in all countries, rich
or poor, against the galloping rise in inequality is often directed at
the dark forces of global intrusion and competition.
To economists, however, it’s unclear how much of the rise in
inequality within a country is due to foreign competition and how much
to the inexorable forces of ongoing technological progress which
contribute to considerable churning in the labor markets in any case:
Computers, robots and ATMs would have displaced secretaries, welders and
bank-tellers, respectively, even in a trade-restricted regime. Such
technology, by raising the demand for skilled and educated labor, turns
the scale against the masses of unskilled workers. There are usually
many other forces operating on the state of income or wealth
distribution in a country. As economic growth itself raises the value of
scarce resources like land, minerals, or oil and gas fields, those
lucky to have ownership rights or enough political connections to
influence public allocation in their favor, have large windfall gains
from rental income, skewing the income distribution in a way that’s not
directly connected with globalization. It’s been estimated, for example,
in India that of the total wealth of its 46 billionaires, in terms of
US dollars, in 2012 60 percent is derived from what’s been called
“rent-thick” sectors, like real estate, construction and infrastructure.
For economists, how much inequality is due to foreign competition or technological progress is unclear. |
In contrast, expansion of exports of mainly skill-intensive products
in India, like pharmaceuticals or software, may have raised inequality.
So the sectoral composition of production matters. Even without
globalization, the usual structural transformation of a developing
country has a substantial impact on inequality. As poor agrarian
countries move away from low productivity but the low-inequality
agricultural sector to high productivity but the high-inequality
manufacturing and services, aggregate inequality rises, largely
independent of globalization. In rich countries the disproportionate
development of the financial sector, helped by but not rooted in
globalization, has made a small number of people extremely wealthy. This
inequality persists through their grip on politics with lobbying power
and campaign finance. In China some of the rumored excessive wealth of
“princelings” and other relatives of Communist Party officials is
derived from private equity firms, apart from real estate. Also, the
Chinese financial sector worsens income distribution by underpaying bank
deposits from ordinary households and using that money for subsidized
loans to business.
Globalization’s impact on inequality depends on education, infrastructure, labor-market conditions. |
Better infrastructure like roads, railways, power and telecommunication enables the poor in remote rural or backward regions to share in gains from expanding jobs in the global sectors and may thus reduce regional and urban-rural inequalities, which constitute a major part of a developing country’s overall inequality.
Domestic labor-market conditions also shape the way the workers adjust. For example, in India there’s some evidence that workers in the low-productivity informal manufacturing sector bore much of the brunt of the increased market competition from trade liberalization in manufacturing. Many of these displaced workers may have then crowded into the non-traded sectors, usually self-employed service, and their conditions may have contributed to increased inequality in a country where the overwhelming majority of the workforce is informal. The relatively few organized workers in India are better situated than the informal workers, but the labor movement there is highly decentralized and fragmented, reducing collective-bargaining strength.
In general, globalization can cause many hardships for the poor, but it also opens up opportunities |
Countries where labor unions are centralized and workers have a
strong safety net of public welfare and job retraining, there is better
bargaining by workers and less resistance to globalization, as in
Scandinavian countries, compared to US or India where labor unions are
usually anti-globalization, with decentralized labor movements and
patchy safety nets.
In some countries globalization may also lead to overexploitation of
fragile local environmental resources – forests, fisheries, water and
more – on which livelihoods of the rural poor depend. But administered
underpricing of some of these resources – like irrigation water in
India, energy in Russia, timber concessions in Indonesia – is a major
factor in resource depletion; domestic vested interests are often
responsible for continuation of such damaging policies.
In general, globalization can cause many hardships for poor people,
but it also opens up opportunities which some countries can utilize and
others do not, largely depending on their domestic political and
economic institutions. The net outcome is often complex and almost
always context-dependent. Serious obstacles to redistributive policies
are often domestic – landlords, corrupt politicians and bureaucrats, and
the currently subsidized rich – and closing the economy does not
usually reduce the power of these interests.
All this means that globalization is often not the main cause of our
problems, contrary to critics’ claims, just as globalization is often
not the main solution of our problems, contrary to the claim of some
overenthusiastic free-traders.
Pranab
Bardhan is professor of the Graduate School at the Department of
Economics, University of California, Berkeley. Of his 12 published books
the latest is Awakening Giants, Feet of Clay: Assessing the Economic
Rise of China and India (Princeton University Press); click here for the excerpt.
No comments:
Post a Comment